OBSERVARE
Universidade Autónoma de Lisboa
e-ISSN: 1647-7251
Vol. 9, Nº. 2 (November 2018-April 2019), pp. 16-31
THEORETICALLY THINKING AND RETHINKING THE INTERNATIONAL ORDER:
THE NEW EMERGING INTERNATIONAL INSTITUTIONS THROUGH NEO-
INSTITUTIONALIST LENSES
Mario Guillermo Guerrero
mgg0921@gmail.com
Ph.D. student in Political Science at the Universidad Nacional de San Martín (UNSAM, Argentina).
Assistant Guest Professor at the Universidad Nacional de Cuyo (UNCuyo).
Abstract
Since the beginning of the 21st century, the emergence of various institutionalization
processes of new informal institutional spaces (such as BRICS, IBSA, BASIC or P5+1) has
been observed internationally, but little has been studied in depth. Accordingly, this paper
seeks to rethink, through a theoretical approach standing between Political Science and
International Relations, the theoretical concepts of neo-institutionalism in order to make a
new critical theoretical-analytical contribution that accounts for the particular characteristics
of such phenomena. We believe that it is of interest for the study of international institutions
to expand the current field of analysis in order to explain how the emergence of these new
institutions occurred and how they interact with already established formal institutions. This
article examines two traditional forms of neo-institutionalism (rational choice neo-
institutionalism and historical neo-institutionalism), making explicit what the starting points
of each are and what elements each can contribute to the study. At the end of the work, a
dialogue is held between the perspectives that allow us to establish a theoretical analytical
criterion to study these new phenomena.
Keywords
International Institutions, Neo-institutionalism, New Emerging Institutions, International
Cooperation, International Organizations
How to cite this article
Guerrero, Mario Guillermo (2018). "Theoretically thinking and rethinking the international
order: the new emerging international institutions through neo-institutionalist lenses".
JANUS.NET e-journal of International Relations, Vol. 9, N.º 2, November 2018-April 2019.
Consulted [online] on the date of the last visit, https://doi.org/10.26619//1647-7251.9.2.2
Article received on December 20, 2017 and accepted for publication on September 1,
2018
JANUS.NET, e-journal of International Relations
e-ISSN: 1647-7251
Vol. 9, Nº. 2 (November 2018-April 2019), pp. 16-31
Theoretically thinking and rethinking the international order:
the new emerging international institutions through neo-institutionalist lenses
Mario Guillermo Guerrero
17
THEORETICALLY THINKING AND RETHINKING THE INTERNATIONAL ORDER:
THE NEW EMERGING INTERNATIONAL INSTITUTIONS THROUGH NEO-
INSTITUTIONALIST LENSES
1
Mario Guillermo Guerrero
2
The literature devoted to the study of international institutions is very prolific (Cox &
Jacobson, 1973; Hass, 1964; Keohane & Nye, 1989; Martin & Simmons, 1998). However,
the greatest criticism has been the fact that international institutions are understood as
synonymous of international organizations and do consider the study of existing informal
international institutions that are in constant interaction with formal institutions (Albaret,
2013; Reinalda, 2013; Simmons & Martin, 2002). Much has been discussed about the
cases of the United Nations (UN), the International Monetary Fund (IMF) or the North
Atlantic Treaty Organization (NATO), but the emergence of new international institutions
in the 21st century such as the BRICS
3
, the G20
4
or the P5 + 1
5
, which have diffuse
temporal horizons, high levels of informality and flexibility, has been little studied
(Albaret, 2013). In historical terms, the particularity of such institutions is that they arise
at a time when large armed confrontations that shook the international sphere, such as
the world wars did, did not occur. Still, critical events took place which questioned the
power of Ikenberry’s victorious States (2001). Examples include the attack on the twin
towers in 2001, the establishment of large terrorist organizations as important
international actors, such as the Islamic State (ISIS) or Al Qaeda, which came to dispute
the state-centric dominance of the international arena, or the 2008-2009 economic and
financial crisis that exposed the main weaknesses of the economic-financial governance
in force (Guerrero, 2017a, 2017b; Patiño Villa, 2012). The informal institutions discussed
here have not only emerged from outside the existing formal institutional structure, but
1
The translation of this article was funded by national funds through FCT - Fundação para a Ciência e
a Tecnologia - as part of OBSERVARE project with the reference UID/CPO/04155/2013, with the aim of
publishing Janus.net. Text translated by Carolina Peralta.
2
The author would like to thank Carlos Acuña, Jorge Battaglino, Julio Leonidas Aguirre, Jacqueline Behrend,
Yesica Kolliker, and Lucio Marinsalda Pastor, as well as the anonymous reviewers, for their comments to
previous drafts of this work.
3
Institutional space composed of Brazil, Russia, India, China and South Africa, which emerged in 2001 within
the framework of the Goldman Sachsresearch programmes but which, over time, was appropriated by the
member countries as their own space, organizing their own summits since 2009.
4
It is a forum created by developing and emerging countries that seek to discuss issues related to
international economic-financial cooperation. The member countries are: Canada, France, Germany, Italy,
Japan, Russia, the United Kingdom and the United States (the latter known as the G8); together with
Argentina, Australia, Brazil, China, India, Indonesia, Mexico, Saudi Arabia, South Africa, South Korea,
Turkey, and the European Union.
5
It is an ad hoc dialogue table established in 2006 for the purpose of negotiating the nuclear issue with Iran.
It was composed of the five permanent members (China, France, Russia, United Kingdom and United States)
with Germany, hence the acronym.
JANUS.NET, e-journal of International Relations
e-ISSN: 1647-7251
Vol. 9, Nº. 2 (November 2018-April 2019), pp. 16-31
Theoretically thinking and rethinking the international order:
the new emerging international institutions through neo-institutionalist lenses
Mario Guillermo Guerrero
18
also their main engineers were emerging or developing countries. This article seeks to
present a theoretical approach standing between Political Science and International
Relations. We believe that it is of interest for the study of international institutions to
expand the current field of analysis through the recovery of the neo-institutionalist
tradition in order to explain how the emergence of these new institutions occurred and
how they interact with already established formal institutions.
Interrogating ourselves on this point is to ask ourselves why the emerging States seek
to build these informal institutions and how they carry out their establishment. To do
this, it is necessary to reflect on the potentialities and weaknesses that neo-
institutionalism presents as a theoretical tool to address the topic suggested here. This
paper seeks to examine two traditional neo-institutionalisms, rational choice neo-
institutionalism (from now on, RCN) and historical neo-institutionalism (from now on,
HN), making explicit what the starting points of each are and what elements each can
contribute to the study. At the end of the article, a dialogue is held between the
perspectives that allow us to establish a theoretical analytical criterion to study these
new phenomena.
I. Stirring in the box of conceptual tools of neo-institutionalisms:
strengths and weaknesses
It is difficult to identify with precision the date when the institutional tradition is born. To
determine which was the first work that addressed this theoretical line is very
complicated, since it is possible to identify various studies capable of being considered
"classical" in the study of institutions. Books such as Plato's "Laws" or Aristotle’s famous
study of the "Athenian Constitutions" are simple examples of how far one can go in an
attempt to identify the roots of this theoretical tradition. According to Rhodes, "[old]
institutionalism is one of the main pillars of political science that focuses on the formal
rules, procedures and organizations of a system of government. Its methodology has an
institutional-descriptive, formal-legal and historical-comparative nature, uses historians’
and jurists’ techniques, and aims to explain both the relationship between structure and
democracy and how rules, procedures and formal organizations determine or not the
political behaviour.” (1997: 65).
However, with the passage of time, the consolidation of Political Science as a scientific
discipline aroused among its scholars a growing interest in delimiting with greater
precision the theoretical scope of the theoretical perspectives that composed it, thus
obliging the successive discipline research to be (or at least seek to be) more precise
about what they wanted to study and how they would carry out this study. At this point,
the intervention of behaviourism played a very important role, marking a before and an
after in the way the standards of scientificity in Political Science were conceived (Sanders,
1997). For this perspective, these criteria went hand in hand with the emphasis on
observable behaviour. Political behaviour was defined as "an orientation or point of view
that seeks to raise all the phenomena of government in terms of observed and observable
behaviour of men" (Immergut, 2006: 389). That is, the interest was placed in the quest
to answer the question of why individuals, institutional actors and nation-states behave
as they do. All these criticisms led to attempts to adapt and/or reformulate the old
institutionalism. The new institutionalism was born from these attempts. This perspective
JANUS.NET, e-journal of International Relations
e-ISSN: 1647-7251
Vol. 9, Nº. 2 (November 2018-April 2019), pp. 16-31
Theoretically thinking and rethinking the international order:
the new emerging international institutions through neo-institutionalist lenses
Mario Guillermo Guerrero
19
seeks to respond to behavioural criticism, while trying to recover the centrality of
institutions for the discipline. The first step was the reconceptualization of the concept of
institution, understanding it in a broader way. However, the broad sense in which
institutions are approached by this perspective is more flexible regarding the old
institutionalism, since they are not perceived in the normative sense they were previously
understood. It is no longer a matter of studying the ideal institutions, but of
understanding the plurality of existing ones and how they affect political behaviour.
According to neo-institutionalism, political behaviour cannot be understood outside the
institutional framework. The latter not only affects (to a greater or lesser extent) the
preferences that guide the actors to act, but also affect the decision-making processes
that they carry out. The breadth with which the concept of institution is worked on in the
new institutionalism resulted in the emergence of a plurality of research programmes
that differ both theoretically and methodologically in the study of institutions, either
understanding them as dependent variables (explaining the emergence and change of
the institutions) or independent ones (explaining what are the effects both in the political
results and in the preferences of the actors that these institutions provoke), according to
the interest of the researcher.
I.a. Rational Choice Neo-institutionalism (RCN)
Within the institutionalist tradition, rational choice neo-institutionalism (RCN) is one of
the most discussed and used institutionalisms in Political Science (Cook & Levi, 1990).
The particularity of this institutionalism is the theoretical debate it has with the
neoclassical theory of political economy, mainly with its behaviour theory and efficient
markets (North, 1990, North & Weingast, 1989). The idea of this dialogue is to overcome
the weakest elements of the perspective by incorporating an institutional theory, which
would allow maintaining what North (1990a: 112) considers the two most significant
conceptual blocks of neoclassical theory (which are scarcity/competition and incentives
as driving forces). At the same time, the theory is modified by recognizing the existence
of incomplete information, subjective models of reality and institutions. For this, North
(1990) proposes an institutional theory based on two pillars: a) a new theory of human
behaviour; and b) a theory of transaction costs.
First, North (1990, 1991, 1998) begins by discussing the concept of instrumental
rationality inherited from neoclassical theory. By such it is understood that "the actors
have correct models to interpret the world that surrounds them; or, that they receive
information that allows them to revise and correct their initially incorrect theories."
(North, 1998: 98). Understanding the rationality of the actors implies that: a) all players
can identify without any problem which are the sources of loss in the search for the
maximization of their benefits; and b) each has equal access to the decision-making
process (North, 1998). Accordingly, given the case of existing actors and organizations
that were not able to have an adequate (i.e. rational) interpretation of the market, they
would be destined to perish in competitive markets due to their inefficient behaviour
(North, 1998).
However, according to North, understanding the rationality of the actors in these terms
would be denying the effect produced by both the motivations and the environment on
the actions conducted by the actors. If these two elements are not taken into account,
JANUS.NET, e-journal of International Relations
e-ISSN: 1647-7251
Vol. 9, Nº. 2 (November 2018-April 2019), pp. 16-31
Theoretically thinking and rethinking the international order:
the new emerging international institutions through neo-institutionalist lenses
Mario Guillermo Guerrero
20
the fact that the actors present particular subjective structures that determine their order
of preferences would be denied, the same applying to denying the existence of problems
when collecting and processing the necessary information to make an efficient decision
in terms of neoclassical theory. It would be tantamount to denying that ideas and
ideologies play an important role in the mental structuring of individuals regarding the
world and how actors act accordingly (North, 1990).
Thus, North proposes a new behaviour theory that refers to a procedural rationality
instead of an instrumental one. The main difference between them is that in the former
the actors "learn by doing" (1998). Through learning by doing, actors carry out decision-
making processes in contexts of imperfect information (due to the subjective models
used, or the impossibility of fully processing information or acquiring all the information),
which prevents them from fully maximizing their benefits in a single movement. But as
the actors participate in various successive games, they are able to obtain more
information about the prevailing rules, which are the most rewarded behaviours (and
which are not), who are the various actors who also intervene in the decision-making
process of a given situation. In short, what should be done to continue maximizing the
benefits (North, 1998).
Secondly, and in a complementary way to the new theory of behaviour developed above,
North (1998) starts by considering a political theory based on the notion of transaction
costs that is built on three assumptions: a) information is expensive; b) the actors use
subjective models to explain their environment; and c) the agreements are only
imperfectly fulfilled. Decisions made using such subjective models have high transaction
costs and make political markets imperfect. Neoclassical theory starts from the
consideration that there is no interference between what an actor needs, his desires and
his action. As proposed by Elster (1990), identifying a certain action as rational implies
recognizing three operations in it: 1) finding the best option for a certain set of beliefs
and desires; 2) creating the best-founded belief set according to the available evidence;
3) Collect the amount of evidence just needed for a certain set of beliefs and desires.
However, the transaction costs theory allows us to understand that the relationship
between desires, beliefs, evidence, and action is not as harmonious as it was believed.
Such a scheme finds its weaknesses in reality facts such as: the non-existence of an
action, evidence or unequivocally optimal belief in a particular case; the possibility that
people may fail either to implement a certain action, form their beliefs, collect evidence
and/or process such evidence (Elster, 1990, North, 1998).
Another aspect that is intimately related to North’s transaction costs theory is the
"cooperation problem" (Olson, 1998). In a context where the actors have important
incentives to distrust what other actors can do due to lack of information, inability to
process the available information, existence of high risks regarding future payments,
difficulty in identifying the free-riders inside a large collective body and the clear non-
identification as to who and how to punish uncooperative behaviour, what incentives could
the actors have to display cooperative behaviour? (North, 1990, 1991, 1998, North &
Weingast, 1989). That is why, based on his theory of procedural rationality and his
transaction costs theory, North believes that an institutional theory would solve the
weaknesses mentioned in previous paragraphs.
JANUS.NET, e-journal of International Relations
e-ISSN: 1647-7251
Vol. 9, Nº. 2 (November 2018-April 2019), pp. 16-31
Theoretically thinking and rethinking the international order:
the new emerging international institutions through neo-institutionalist lenses
Mario Guillermo Guerrero
21
For this author, an institution is the set of "humanly designed constraints that structure
political, economic and social interaction. They are both informal constraints (sanctions,
taboos, customs, traditions and codes of conduct) and formal rules (constitutions, laws,
property rights)”
6
(North, 1991: 1). Institutions make it possible to reduce uncertainties
in the exchange. They define the set of available options and therefore determine
transaction and production costs for a given time and space. The latter does not mean
that the actors wishes or beliefs are structured by the institutions, but rather that the
preferences continue to be thought of as exogenous within the institutional analytical
framework of the author (North, 1990a: 111).
However, if the actors intend to maximize their benefits, they must take into account the
incentives (both positive and negative) that the institutional (particularly economic)
structure presents. In particular, what interests North is to see how the relationship
between the subjective frameworks of the actors and the institutions occurs, since
understanding this relationship means understanding how it has translated into various
economic-political institutional frameworks throughout history. This way, if we take the
schematization made by Fioretos, Falleti & Sheingate (2016), who drew a chart that
shows two central dimensions (on the one hand the structure-actor continuum, and on
the other the interest-idea continuum) to be able to compare the two neo-
institutionalisms, we can affirm that the RCN is a theoretical perspective focused on
actors and that it adopts a base centred on interests (see Chart 1).
6
Author’s own translation
JANUS.NET, e-journal of International Relations
e-ISSN: 1647-7251
Vol. 9, Nº. 2 (November 2018-April 2019), pp. 16-31
Theoretically thinking and rethinking the international order:
the new emerging international institutions through neo-institutionalist lenses
Mario Guillermo Guerrero
22
In North's institutionalist theory, institutions are a tool to solve the cooperation problems
between actors. This is due to the fact that institutions allow reducing the uncertainties
that surround all human actions. The norms, the rules and the procedures (whether
formal or informal) make it possible to simplify the process according to which the actors
make decisions in a changing context, where obtaining information is costly even in the
processing of the information one has. In particular, institutions allow solving the
cooperation problem, since they establish incentives (both positive and negative) that
reward and punish the actor’s behaviour. This forces the actors who seek to survive and
continue to maximize their benefits to comply with the established set of norms, rules
and procedures: otherwise, they will be sanctioned and the competitiveness itself would
be seriously deteriorated.
For North, the central axis of Political Economy is to be able to account for the evolution
of economic and political institutions that create an economic environment capable of
inducing increasing productivity (North, 1990, 1991). Within this analytical scheme, what
happens with history? Although North intends to explain how the evolution of political
and economic institutions occurs, in his analyses history is a tool to illustrate his
hypothesis and not so much the main element of institutional analysis. At this point, it is
interesting to bring back the comments made by Pierson (2004) regarding the various
ways history can be used in an analysis. One of the most used, and particularly in regard
to rational choice theories, is the concept of "history as the hunt for illustrative material".
History is used as a reservoir of illustrative cases where the researcher seeks to find
examples that allow him to account for the theoretical-empirical scope of his explanatory
models. However, in these cases the analyses say very little (or nothing) about the
temporal dimensions of the political-social processes (Pierson, 2004: 5). The latter is
very often seen in North's works. Examples include the work carried out by North &
Weingast (1989), where they question the constraints placed by the English Parliament
on the Crown during the seventeenth century, or the use of merchant caravans or Souks
in the Arabian Peninsula as examples of "primitive" and unproductive markets (North,
1990, 1991). Therefore, in North's analysis there is not much interest in giving an account
of what the explanatory role of the temporal dimension in the development of institutions
is, but rather in identifying what the different institutions that have developed in history
have been and how they have contributed (or not) to an increase in productivity in a
particular society.
Even the non-consideration of the temporal dimension in the political-social processes as
an explanatory variable Pierson speaks of can be observed if we take into account North’s
explanation of why institutions change (or not). The institutions persist because they are
useful for the actors. When these ceases to be, the actors decide to change them for
another set. But this change is gradual and occurs as a result of the actors' incessant
actions. The latter is possible because North assumes the concept of a Schumpeterian
entrepreneur, who, as he gains more knowledge and develops greater capabilities,
together with great advances in the technological structure and prices, changes his
preferences and seeks to make institutional changes that allow them to be maximized
(North, 1990). However, in the short term the maximization of the actors’ interests is
guaranteed by institutional stability. The source of this stability is the institutional path
dependence. Here the path dependence concept is not understood in the terms of
historical neo-institutionalism, but rather as the institutions’ ability to generate increasing
JANUS.NET, e-journal of International Relations
e-ISSN: 1647-7251
Vol. 9, Nº. 2 (November 2018-April 2019), pp. 16-31
Theoretically thinking and rethinking the international order:
the new emerging international institutions through neo-institutionalist lenses
Mario Guillermo Guerrero
23
returns and give stability over time to the norms, rules and procedures that constrain the
performance of the actors (North, 1990, 83). Accordingly, through successive games, the
actor can acquire information that allows him to understand not only the behaviour that
a certain institutional framework rewards but also the ways such institutional frameworks
can be altered in order to maximize other types of interests.
In short, the main wealth of the RCN as a theoretical perspective is that it adopts an
analysis based on actors and interests, in which the actors, according to their
exogenously established preferences, decide to select and build (formal and informal)
institutions that allow them to reduce transaction costs and the information costs they
face on a daily basis when it comes to maximizing their benefits. Thus, institutions are
presented as synonyms of stability, a stability that limits the range of actions available
to actors when deploying their behaviour, but under no conditions such institutions shape
preferences, ideas and/or interests (Hall & Taylor, 1996, Immergut, 2006). Perhaps the
main difference between the RCN and the HN is precisely how they understand the
establishment of preferences (Orfeo Fioretos et al., 2016).
I.b. Historical Neo-institutionalism (HN)
Historical neo-institutionalism (HN) is characterized by understanding institutions as
procedures, routines, norms and formal and informal conventions of politics and political
economy (Hall & Taylor, 1996). However, the biggest difference from the RCN is that here
institutions "are always constellations that combine rules with cultural, geographic and
historically specific norms, value beliefs, formal organizations, and social practices.
Institutions are complex structures that link action. An institution is not a monolith, but
a system of social factors that together generate a regularity of action" (Katznelson,
2009, 109). Seen from this perspective, institutions are presented as structuring
preferences and choices (paths) (Hall & Taylor, 1996, Immergut, 2006, Katznelson, 2009,
Pierson & Skocpol, 2008; Thelen, 1999).
For this perspective, the various institutional schemes that characterize political-
economic structures in a given historical context are the product of the struggle of various
actors for the distribution of scarce resources. Therefore, the institutions reflect the
crystallization of the results of these struggles. For this reason, historical institutionalism
considers it interesting to carry out an analysis at meso-macro level that allows
identifying the multiple institutions in an interaction that operate in broader contexts.
Institutions are not considered in an isolated and separate way, but as being in constant
interrelation and superimposed on each other, configuring a framework or institutional
network (Orfeo Fioretos et al., 2016, Hall & Taylor, 1996). The historical institutionalists
“analyse how groups of organizations and institutions relate to each
other and shape the processes or results of interest. (...) The results
are generated not by some apparent universal principle
characteristic of a given type of actor or area of activity, but by
intersections of organized practices. These practices often originated
at different times and, therefore, configurations that give advantage
to certain key actors would have developed. These actors work to
JANUS.NET, e-journal of International Relations
e-ISSN: 1647-7251
Vol. 9, Nº. 2 (November 2018-April 2019), pp. 16-31
Theoretically thinking and rethinking the international order:
the new emerging international institutions through neo-institutionalist lenses
Mario Guillermo Guerrero
24
maintain the configuration while the economic, cultural and
geopolitical circumstances change" (Pierson & Skocpol, 2008: 20).
The key question that historical institutionalism asks is: why do certain structures or
patterns take shape at certain times and places, while others do not? Historical
institutionalists are interested in developing time-based arguments that allow
understanding the temporality and sequence of the various political phenomena that we
intend to study, since these are understood as political processes. The fact that they are
perceived as such implies that these phenomena are not studied as a simple "photograph"
of a given situation, but rather intend to trace transformations and processes of varying
scale and temporality. "Historical institutionalists go through a constant back and forth
movement between cases, questions and hypotheses" (Pierson & Skocpol, 2008: 10).
Accordingly, the problems that matter come from identifying real-world variations
previously unexplained or from noticing that empirical patterns go against popular and
academically established concepts. As previously mentioned, historical institutionalists
do not have totalizing ambitions, nor do they seek to understand the historical-universal
dynamics of the political phenomena. Instead, they seek to identify the historical
dimensions of causality. This means that "statements about the existence of causal
relationships should be supported not only by a correlation between two variables, but
also by a theory that would show why this connection should exist, as well as by evidence
that would support this theoretical connection" (Pierson & Skocpol, 2008: 12). To this
effect, the analyses start from the consideration of a small N, which allows a detailed
examination of the processes that can facilitate the evaluation of assertions about causal
mechanisms; and, on the other hand, of causal arguments, with a theoretical basis on
causal relations that generally imply particular time-based relationships between
variables, where one precedes the other, or both take place essentially at the same time.
A series of central concepts allow establishing this set of causal arguments: sequence,
path dependence, and critical conjuncture.
On the one hand, a key concept in the present perspective is that of "sequence". The
order in which events occur matters, since a fundamental difference can arise from it.
The answer to the question why one phenomenon occurred at a given moment and not
another may lie in the sequence (Falleti & Mahoney, 2016, Pierson & Skocpol, 2008).
Therefore, the sequences have a lot to do with the positive feedback process. This is due
to the fact that depending on how the order of events takes place, this will influence the
different reproduction mechanisms adopted for a given trajectory.
When the HN uses the concept of path dependence (or trajectory dependence), it refers
to the dynamics of positive feedback processes in a political system" (Pierson & Skocpol,
2008: 12). This means that institutions are consolidated as they are set in motion. The
implementation of a particular institution makes it adopt an institutional inertia that leads
it to strengthen the chosen institutional trajectory. Thus, institutions become less prone
to change over time, and this is only possible in the presence of critical conjunctures.
The richness of this concept allows us to study how the actors choose different paths and
how, with the implementation of various institutional decisions, the institutions move
away from, or approach what the actors thought in the first instance.
JANUS.NET, e-journal of International Relations
e-ISSN: 1647-7251
Vol. 9, Nº. 2 (November 2018-April 2019), pp. 16-31
Theoretically thinking and rethinking the international order:
the new emerging international institutions through neo-institutionalist lenses
Mario Guillermo Guerrero
25
As already mentioned, for the HN the institutions should not be understood as
"monolithic" structures that are completely rigid against any type of change (Katznelson,
2009). The concept of critical conjuncture introduces a dynamic argument in the
institutional historical analysis, since it suggests that a series of small or large events can
reconfigure the path or trajectory that had been chosen in the beginning and give rise to
a new dispute over resources involving the various actors, resulting in a new institutional
configuration. There are many works that use this concept to refer to large scale
phenomena or events to explain the emergence of new path dependence dynamics, but
such dramatic situation is not a necessary nor sufficient condition to be considered a
critical conjuncture: what makes a particular conjuncture critical is the fact that it triggers
a positive feedback process, regardless of its "size" (Pierson & Skocpol, 2008).
Taken together, all these concepts allow us to study the weight of the temporal dimension
within a given explanation that accounts for a relevant socio-political phenomenon. Such
concepts force us to think about the causal sequence that connects our phenomenon-
result of interest (dependent variable) with those events and processes that intervened
in such result (Falleti & Mahoney, 2016). Thinking about causal mechanisms like this
enables understanding why a certain institutional framework emerges at a certain time
and place, while in others it does not. The path dependence permits understanding how
institutions endure over time and space, even though the initial conditions that facilitated
their emergence have disappeared. The critical conjuncture allows us to study how
institutional changes occur in those institutions that were believed to be difficult to
change. In addition, it allows understanding how actors seek to create new institutional
frameworks that make them keep the new power obtained after a critical conjuncture
and how such frameworks tend to be established in a completely different way from those
originally conceived (Thelen, 1999). All these are just examples of how, by introducing
temporality as an explanatory dimension, we can obtain a completely different analysis
than what is proposed by the RCN.
An aspect to take into account when carrying out an institutional analysis from the
perspective of the HN is to avoid falling into the trap of explanatory rigidity that
"institutions explain everything" (Acuña & Chudnovsky, 2013). When conducting a study
of institutions resorting to HN, it is often tempting to think of institutional changes and
reproductions as devoid of actors, since the latter are subsumed to the dynamics of
institutions that overcome them, which often leads to thinking tautological causal
relationships. This difficulty can be overcome if one establishes precisely which are the
elements that make up the causal mechanism that links the independent variable(s) with
the dependent variable (Falleti & Mahoney, 2016).
II. What contributions can neo-institutionalism make to the study of the
new emerging international institutions?
The specialized literature suggests that the institutionalization of the associative
dynamics among the agents increases their cooperation and collective action (Hall &
Taylor, 1996; Immergut, 2006; North, 1990; North & Weingast, 1989), even when we
talk about international cooperation between nations (Axelrod & Keohane, 1985).
However, little has been done to study the institutionalization processes of informal
institutions initiated at the beginning of the century. Faced with this, it becomes relevant
JANUS.NET, e-journal of International Relations
e-ISSN: 1647-7251
Vol. 9, Nº. 2 (November 2018-April 2019), pp. 16-31
Theoretically thinking and rethinking the international order:
the new emerging international institutions through neo-institutionalist lenses
Mario Guillermo Guerrero
26
to (re)think about the theoretical contributions of neo-institutionalism in order to have a
critical theoretical-analytical criterion that accounts for these new phenomena.
To begin with, the concept discussed here is that of an international institution. Although
there is diverse literature that expands and works on the concept, the conceptual
discussion suggested here brings back three approaches: idealism, liberal institutionalism
and historical neo-institutionalism.
The traditional idealist school of international relations emphasizes formal international
institutions (Judge, 1977; Schechter, 2010; Simmons & Martin, 2002). An international
institution is defined as any institution in which the following three elements can be
identified simultaneously (Judge, 1977): 1) be based on an agreement which is formally
implemented by the governments of different nation-states; 2) include three or more
nation-states as members of the agreement; 3) have a permanent secretariat with its
own autonomous tasks and activities. As can be seen in the previous definition, the
literature associates international institutions with international organizations (Simmons
& Martin, 2002). The latter is not surprising since the greatest proliferation of the formal
literature emerged in the period between world wars, and the main elements of empirical
observation are the League of Nations (LN) and the United Nations Organization (UN). In
addition, one notes that the concept is thought in terms of being able to evaluate the
autonomy of a particular organization with respect to the States that create them. This
is described by Schechter (2010) as the greater or lesser capacity on the part of the
organization to establish and develop a bureaucracy that works separately and is
functionally autonomous with respect to the countries that created it. This is so because
such organizations were thought of as third parties in the resolution of peace and war
conflicts. The greatest weakness of this concept is the confusion between institution and
organization. The latter not only does not allow us to observe the effects that rules,
procedures and norms can produce on international actors, but also it does not allow us
to observe the role of rules, norms and informal procedures that come into play and of
the formal ones in the international scenario.
A second tradition is related to institutional analyses known in International Relations as
liberal institutionalism (Axelrod & Keohane, 1985, Keohane & Martin, 1995). Since the
beginning of the 21st century, the international scenario has seen an exponential increase
regarding the creation of international institutions that do not have the three previously
mentioned characteristics (Albaret, 2013; Reinalda, 2013). Observing this phenomenon
is only possible if the concept of international institutions previously presented is
broadened. According to Keohane & Nye (1989: 3), international institutions are the
persistent and interconnected set of rules (formal and informal) that prescribe roles of
behaviour, constrain the actors activity and define their expectations. The greatest
weakness of this concept is that international institutions are understood as static
elements. Most of the literature in this tradition has been dedicated to the study of the
effect that international institutions have on the commercial exchange between countries
(McLaughlim Mitchell & Hensel, 2007) or on armed conflicts (Keohane & Martin, 1995,
Keohane & Nye, 1989). In all these works, the absence of temporality as an explanatory
dimension of the phenomena to be explained is constant.
It is for this reason that studies from a historical neo-institutionalist perspective have
gained important ground in recent years in the study of international institutions. In this
JANUS.NET, e-journal of International Relations
e-ISSN: 1647-7251
Vol. 9, Nº. 2 (November 2018-April 2019), pp. 16-31
Theoretically thinking and rethinking the international order:
the new emerging international institutions through neo-institutionalist lenses
Mario Guillermo Guerrero
27
tradition, we have authors such as John Ikenberry (2001) and Orfeo Fioretos (2011). For
example, a large part of the work of John Ikenberry (2001, 2014) has focused on how
the processes of establishing international political orders occurred throughout history. in
his book After Victory (Ikenberry, 2001), the author begins by wondering about what the
States that have just won great wars do with the newly acquired power. Taking these
questions as a basis, After Victory is a work structured around the consideration of three
critical global conjunctures (1815, 1919 and 1945), which allow explaining the
consequent emergence of institutional frameworks as a deliberate product of the
victorious states. Ikenberry's hypothesis is that each of these critical junctures, by being
a point of completion of major armed conflicts worldwide, presented unique opportunities
for the establishment of international institutional agreements that were capable of tying-
linking states to each other. The main characteristic of such institutional frameworks was
that they generated a lock-in effect with respect to the dominant and favourable position
obtained by the victorious states. At the same time, they left certain institutional spaces
in which the loser and/or weaker states could deploy strategic behaviour. Accordingly,
the international institutions allowed the victorious states both to maintain control over
the international agenda and the orientation of the main foreign policies with the
consequent primary action on these issues and to grant the other states some credible
and institutionalized control tools that limit the power gained by the victorious states
(Ikenberry, 2001). As a result of these dynamics, international organizations like the
United Nations (UN), the International Monetary Fund (IMF) or the World Bank (WB) were
created, which sought to become the main channel for resolving all types of international
conflict but which, at the same time, reproduced inside the victorious condition obtained
by some countries after each conjuncture (for example, the establishment of the United
States, the United Kingdom, France, Russia and China as permanent members of the
United Nations Security Council).
Regarding the new emerging institutions, since the beginning of the 21st century, the
international scenario has seen an exponential increase in the creation of informal
international institutions that do not have Judge’s three characteristics (Albaret, 2013;
Reinalda, 2013). From a conceptual point of view, these new informal institutions have
the following characteristics:
Non-existence of a selection process open to all states: participation in such
institutions is voluntary, but not universal, since to be part of them is subject to
invitation.
They are multilateral but with small N: this means that these institutions are not
thought about in the same universalist way that the main international institutions
of the period between war or post-cold war were seen, but rather as smaller number
of states than the UN or the WB and usually closely linked to the theme or function
for which the institution was created.
They are highly flexible: they do not denote the high levels of bureaucratization that
the UN or the WB have, but they are spaces for deliberation where the member
states can establish rapprochement policies on particular topics and in an ad hoc
manner.
JANUS.NET, e-journal of International Relations
e-ISSN: 1647-7251
Vol. 9, Nº. 2 (November 2018-April 2019), pp. 16-31
Theoretically thinking and rethinking the international order:
the new emerging international institutions through neo-institutionalist lenses
Mario Guillermo Guerrero
28
All these elements do nothing but raise questions such as: why do states create this type
of international institutions? What changes did occur in the international scenario that
facilitated their emergence? What is the role of these new informal institutions? What
changes did take place in the functional dynamics of traditional international institutions,
such as the UN, the IMF or the WB, that facilitated the emergence of these new
international institutions? What were the main obstacles and difficulties that the states
had to address when creating these new institutional spaces? Observing this phenomenon
is only possible if the concept of international institutions that was previously presented
is expanded, alongside the approach with which their study is carried out.
As can be seen, the study of international institutions has been carried out from different
perspectives. In the first place, there has been a confusion between the concepts of
international organization and international institution, which meant that research
programmes only studied the characteristics of international organizations in force at that
time. On the other hand, in Keohane’s & Nye’s approach (1989), the agency capacity of
the states begins to play a central role in the explanation of the various international
institutions that prevail. However, the greatest weakness of this analysis is that it has
difficulty in explaining the emergence and evolution over time of institutions due to their
static view of them. The latter is a point that historical neo-institutionalism seeks to
strengthen, suggesting the study of the international institutional framework through its
instituting dynamics, such as path dependence and its change moments through critical
conjunctures. But in many of their explanations, the agency capacity of the actors loses
explanatory weight, often going to the extreme of affirming that the institutions can
explain everything (Acuña & Chudnovsky, 2013). At this point, the dialogue between
perspectives seems to suggest that there is analytical richness in the conciliation of both
perspectives. Given the particularities of the institutionalization processes led by the
emerging countries, resorting to the states agency capacity without renouncing the
temporality of the phenomenon would allow identifying how such processes are similar
or distant from those initiated by central countries.
This article suggests addressing the problem through the revival of the state’s centrality
in the construction of institutions proposed by liberal institutionalism. It also rationalizes
the historicity of the phenomenon through the incorporation of temporality into the study
of the emerging states’ action involved in the constitution of these new institutional
spaces. Accordingly, one could study the effect of the important variables that came into
play during the negotiation period regarding a given institutional project, such as: 1) the
existence of a homogeneity of interests in the member states; and 2) the establishment
of a feeling of trust between the member states. In addition, as regards temporality, the
sustained increase in the interactions between member states is suggested as the third
variable. A fourth, and last, variable could be the fulfilment of the previously established
institutional objectives. This would be a key dimension in terms of explaining whether
there was a positive or negative development or even stagnation in the process of
institutionalizing such initiatives. For example, keeping these variables in mind could
address with greater precision the institutionalization processes of the various regional
institutions, such as the Common Market of the South (MERCOSUR), the Union of South
American Nations (UNASUR), and the Bolivarian Alliance for the Peoples of Our America
(ALBA) in South America without having to fall into the "N = 1 problem" generated by
JANUS.NET, e-journal of International Relations
e-ISSN: 1647-7251
Vol. 9, Nº. 2 (November 2018-April 2019), pp. 16-31
Theoretically thinking and rethinking the international order:
the new emerging international institutions through neo-institutionalist lenses
Mario Guillermo Guerrero
29
the European Union as a normative model in the explanation of any type of regional
integration (Malamud, 2011).
Taken together, these variables would make it possible to account for the political-
institutional conditions according to which emerging countries have constituted these
new institutional spaces, since they address the phenomenon taking into account their
informal institutionalization in high volatility contexts in the international scenario, while
at the same time addressing them in their historical rationality.
III. Brief Final Comments
In a field of study where the idealist and realistic perspectives have hegemonized the
theoretical-empirical discussion, any approach to international problems from an
institutionalist perspective implies a novel work. The latter increases its novel character
if one takes into account the few studies carried out about the informal international
institutions that emerged at the beginning of the 21st century. Understanding how
international actors, mainly states, resolve their collective action dilemmas in the
international arena from a view that rationalizes the historicity of such processes involves
conducting studies that go beyond the traditional study of international organizations.
This article aimed to discuss new conceptual tools that allow studying how the sequences
of changes in the international institutional framework occur and identifying in particular
the role played by international actors, institutions, and temporality in such a sequence.
IV. References
Acuña, C., & Chudnovsky, M. (2013). Cómo entender las instituciones y su relación con
la política. Lo bueno, lo malo y lo feo de las instituciones y los institucionalismos. En C.
Acuña & M. Chudnovsky (Eds.), ¿Cuánto importan las instituciones? Gobierno, Estado y
actores en la política argentina. (pp. 1967). Buenos Aires: Siglo XXI.
Albaret, M. (2013). Multilateralism under transformation. International organizations and
“clubs”. In B. Reinalda (Ed.), Routledge Handbook of International Organization (pp.
512523). New York: Routledge.
Axelrod, R., & Keohane, R. (1985). Achieving Cooperation under Anarchy: strategies and
institutions. World Politics, 38(1), 226254.
Cook, K., & Levi, M. (1990). The Limits of Rationality. Chicago: The University of Chicago
Press.
Cox, R. W., & Jacobson, H. K. (1973). The Anatomy of Influence: decision making in
international organization, by Robert W. Cox and Harold K. Jacobson, and [others]. Yale
University Press New Haven.
Elster, J. (1990). When Rationality Fails. In K. Cook & M. Levi (Eds.), The Limits of
Rationality (pp. 1951). Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.
Falleti, T., & Mahoney, J. (2016). El método secuencial comparado. Revista SAAP, 10(2),
187220.
JANUS.NET, e-journal of International Relations
e-ISSN: 1647-7251
Vol. 9, Nº. 2 (November 2018-April 2019), pp. 16-31
Theoretically thinking and rethinking the international order:
the new emerging international institutions through neo-institutionalist lenses
Mario Guillermo Guerrero
30
Fioretos, O. (2011). Historical Institutionalism in International Relations. International
Organization, 65(02), 367–399. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0020818311000002
Fioretos, O., Falleti, T., & Sheingate, A. (2016). Historical Institutionalism in Political
Science. In O. Fioretos, T. Falleti, & A. Sheingate (Eds.), The Oxford Handbook of
Historical Institutionalism (pp. 18–49). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Guerrero, M. G. (2017a). BRICS: proceso de institucionalización de un nuevo actor
colectivo en el sistema internacional (periodo 2001 - 2015). Universidad Nacional de
Cuyo.
Guerrero, M. G. (2017b). Congruencia del BRICS en la Agenda de Seguridad
Internacional: El Caso Siria (periodo 2011 - 2015). Buenos Aires: XIII Congreso Nacional
de Ciencia Política.
Hall, P., & Taylor, R. (1996). La ciencia política y los tres nuevos institucionalismos.
Political Studies, 44, 936957.
Hass, E. B. (1964). Beyond the Nation-State: Functionalism and International
Organization. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Ikenberry, G. J. (2001). After Victory: Institutions, Strategic Restraint, and the Rebuilding
of Order after Major Wars (STU-Stud). Princeton University Press. Retrieved from
http://www.jstor.org/stable/j.ctt7t1s5
Ikenberry, G. J. (2014). Power, Order, and Change in World Politics. Cambridge
University Press.
Immergut, E. (2006). El núcleo teórico del nuevo institucionalismo. In V. Alarcón Olguín
(Ed.), Metodología para el análisis político. Enfoques, procesos e instituciones. (pp. 387
424). Mexico: Universidad Autónoma Metropolitana.
Judge, A. (1977). International Institutions: diversity, borderline cases, functional
substitutes and possible alternatives. In P. Taylor & A. Groom (Eds.), International
Organisation: a conceptual approach (pp. 2883). London: Frances Pinter Ltd.
Katznelson, I. (2009). Strong theory, Complex History. In M. Lichbach & A. Zuckerman
(Eds.), Comparative Politics: Rationality, Culture, and Structure, Second Edition (pp. 96
116). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511804007
Keohane, R. O., & Martin, L. L. (1995). The Promise of Institutionalist Theory.
International Security, 20(1), 3951. https://doi.org/10.2307/2539214
Keohane, R. O., & Nye, J. (1989). Power and Interdependence. Glenview: Scott,
Foresman and Company.
Malamud, A. (2011). Conceptos, teorías y debates sobre la integración regional.
Norteamérica, 2, 219–249.
Martin, L. L., & Simmons, B. A. (1998). Theories and Empirical Studies of International
Institutions. International Organization, 52(4), 729757.
https://doi.org/10.1162/002081898550734
JANUS.NET, e-journal of International Relations
e-ISSN: 1647-7251
Vol. 9, Nº. 2 (November 2018-April 2019), pp. 16-31
Theoretically thinking and rethinking the international order:
the new emerging international institutions through neo-institutionalist lenses
Mario Guillermo Guerrero
31
McLaughlim Mitchell, S., & Hensel, P. (2007). International Institutions and Compliance
with Agreements. American Journal of Political Science, 51(4), 721737.
North, D. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
North, D. (1991). Institutions. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1), 97112.
https://doi.org/10.2307/2234910
North, D. (1998). Una teoría de la política basada en el enfoque de los costos de
transacción. In S. Saiegh & M. Tommasi (Eds.), La nueva economía política (pp. 97–112).
Buenos Aires: EUDEBA.
North, D., & Weingast, B. (1989). Constitutions and Commitment: the evolution of
institutional governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. The Journal of
Economic History, 49(4), 808832.
Olson, M. (1998). La Lógica de la Acción Colectiva. In S. Saiegh & M. Tommasi (Eds.), La
nueva economía política (pp. 3762). Buenos Aires: EUDEBA.
Patiño Villa, C. (2012). De la bipolaridad al fracaso de la unipolaridad. Analecta política,
1(1 Jul-Dec), 3361.
Pierson, P. (2004). Politics in Time: History, Institutions, and Social Analysis. Princeton:
Princeton University Press. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1537592705520255
Pierson, P., & Skocpol, T. (2008). El institucionalismo histórico en la ciencia política
contemporánea. Revista Uruguaya de Ciencia Política, 17(1), 7–38.
Reinalda, B. (2013). International Organizations as a field of research since 1910. En B.
Reinalda (Ed.), Routledge Handbook of International Organization (pp. 1–23). New York:
Routledge.
Rhodes, R. (1997). El institucionalismo. En D. Marsh & G. Stoker (Eds.), Teoría y métodos
de la ciencia política (pp. 5367). Madrid: Alianza Universidad.
Sanders, D. (1997). El análisis conductista. En D. Marsh & G. Stoker (Eds.), Teoría y
métodos de la ciencia política (pp. 69–84). Madrid: Alianza Universidad.
Schechter, M. G. (2010). Historical Dictionary of International Organizations (Second
Edi). Plymouth: The Scarecrow Press. Retrieved from www.scarecrowpress.com
Simmons, B., & Martin, L. (2002). International Organizations and Institutions. En
Handbook of International Relations (pp. 256281). London: SAGE.
Thelen, K. (1999). Historical institutionalism in comparative politics. Annual Review of
Political Science, 2, 369404.